jump to navigation

Google’s RE<C: Making the Perfect the Enemy of the Good? February 4, 2008

Posted by Michael Hoexter in Renewable Energy, Sustainable Thinking.
Tags: , , , , , ,
trackback

I’ve generally applauded or appreciated Google’s initiatives in the area of climate and energy. Among large technology firms, Google has seemed to have gotten the basic outlines of the future renewable electron economy. For one, they embraced carbon neutrality pretty early in the game. For two, they have located at least one of their server facilities so as to take advantage of clean hydro and purchased one of the larger photovoltaic arrays in the world for their Mountain View HQ. Thirdly, they’ve assembled some, what from all reports are, pretty energy efficient “blade” servers for internal use and have been leaders in the Climate Savers Computing Initiative. Fourthly, they have been supportive of electric drive transportation, in particular plug in hybrids. Furthermore Larry and Sergey have put their own money into some of the Valley’s more promising energy plays, including Nanosolar and Tesla Motors.

However, when Google announced RE<C in late November, the clean energy industry and climate policy community was delivered something akin to the Apple of Discord or Pandora’s Box, a tempting, shiny but divisive and potentially destructive gift (in fact the German word for poison is “Gift”…coincidence? I think not!). While Google had received almost universal applause for its previous initiatives, here was a still splashier and more ambitious clean energy/climate project that leaves a slightly bitter taste in the mouths of many of Google’s current and would-be allies.

To those who are not aware of RE<C, I can give you a short, perhaps biased summary of its intent but you can find the official version at the Google.org website. RE<C means “renewable energy cheaper than (less than) coal”. The intention of RE<C is to make renewable energy so cheap that everybody in the world can afford it, thereby out-competing climate-altering coal on price. Cheaper than coal means from one to three cents per kilowatt-hour, which is compared to the price of energy from old, “paid-for” rather than new coal plants. The timeframe for this transformative vision is a period of years rather than decades. Google has already invested $20 million dollars in RE<C, $10 million each to the solar thermal electric start-up eSolar, an Idealab company and Makani Power, Inc, a high-altitude kite-based wind turbine company. In addition to these technologies, Google has expressed an interest in Enhanced Geothermal Systems technology, a way to scale up geothermal from specialized hot spots to almost every location. RE<C is an initiative that is housed in Google’s venture philanthropy, Google.org, which is led by Larry Brilliant, the medical doctor who among other things, helped in the effort to eradicate smallpox.

Replace Coal?

One of the ambiguities of the RE<C announcement is whether the new Google renewable power plant will function as a coal replacement. Coal-fired power plants take a while to start and stop and they are cheap to run so they are used for always-on baseload power that operates day and night. Sometimes pulverized coal plants are used to follow the load, meaning gradually increasing and decreasing power output to meet the daily rise in power demand. RE<C is to produce one gigawatt of power generating capacity at a price cheaper than coal yet it is not clear whether this will be an “always-on” solution that replaces the functions of typical coal plants. One of the challenges for most renewable energies has been the lack of controllability and variations in the strength and availability in the renewable “fuel” for the electric generator; the sun shines during the day, wind blows intermittently. So, while it is implied that the new Google renewables will replace the function of coal plants on the grid, this goal is not stated in what has been made public so far.

RE<C and the Cheap Energy Contract

RE<C assents to the continuation of what I called in my latest post in the Renewable Electron Economy series, “The Cheap Energy Contract”. The Cheap Energy Contract is an implicit social contract that requires that non-food energy be cheap, really cheap. Not only does this contract require natural and technological conditions that allow energy to be cheap but also it is a “contract” because political leaders are on the hook to ensure that energy remains cheap. This contract is in particular force in the United States and Canada but, by dint of lower per-capita income and high demand, it can be said to be in force in China and India, two of the new industrial giants. One can say that industrialization requires at least moderately priced if not cheap energy; otherwise food-powered human labor or feed-powered animal work would be able to economically compete with the output of machines powered by electricity, gas or coal.

The Cheap Energy Contract has come under fire recently from a number of quarters, most notably governments and activists concerned about global warming. The measures proposed, cap and trade or carbon tax, are meant to raise the price of fossil energy to allow clean energy sources, mostly renewables, to compete. In some countries and proposed here in the US, feed-in tariffs function as a New Energy Contract in which renewable electric generators receive higher wholesale electric rates to support their growth, adding somewhat to electricity prices. Finally, climbing fossil fuel prices may endanger the Cheap Energy Contract as oil and natural gas move towards or pass their peak.

RE<C conforms to the existing valuation of energy, be it clean or dirty: it is good and right that it is cheap. Given that one would think Google’s leaders would be allied with the movement against climate change, the position of RE<C is surprising. Furthermore, it appears that Google’s policy guru, Dan Reicher has also been spreading the cheap energy love lately, so RE<C has become the Google energy mantra. Nordhaus and Shellenberger in their book BreakThrough, concur with the cheap energy requirement but suggest that government subsidy plays a very big role in keeping energy cheap, as well as helping spur new innovation. Google’s RE<C seems to suggest that the government spending will not be as crucial, as heroic inventors will make it all happen on their own.

RE<C as Aid to the Developing World

One of the emphases within the initial announcement and now in recent public discussion at the 2008 Economic Forum at Davos, has been the motivation of Larry Brilliant and the two Google founders to make clean energy affordable for the developing world. In the, supposedly inspiring, words of Larry Brilliant:

“You can’t succeed just out of conservation because then you won’t have economic development. Find a way to make electricity — not to cut back on it but to have more of it than you ever dreamed of.”

The Davos Forum is a place where the glitterati and technorati like to emphasize the charitable aspects of their activity, but the theme of “the China price” has cropped up in most news conferences on RE<C. At Davos, Larry Page also talked somewhat dismissively of clean energy that is produced at 10 cents per kilowatt-hour, saying that this did not change much in the world.

Techno-pessimists vs. Techno-optimists?

Apparently at Davos, preceding the session with the Googlers, Al Gore and Bono had just been talking about putting a price on carbon. At one point, in Jeff Jarvis’s account of the Google RE<C session, a kind of shadow dispute occurred between Gore in the audience and Brilliant about the nature of the opposition to clean power. The more substantive policy dispute about the acceptable price of clean energy remained unspoken.

At least in Jarvis’s account, but also apparently in the Google guys’ own thinking, they see themselves as technological optimists or just plain optimists, fighting the good fight against those who are obsessed with regulation. Jarvis in his account of his own contribution to the session

“I say from the floor that I see a cultural difference between the movement and Google on this. Google has the positive message of the potential for change through technology. I ask about how they are going to get this message out to encourage investment from government and the public.”

The framing of the debate in these terms was very friendly to the Google folks’ point of view, as Gore and “the movement” appeared to be standing in the way of progress, while the Google folk were simply putting themselves in the position to bring energy to the masses.

RE<C: A Reality Check

The orgy of self-congratulation that seems to be accompanying RE<C has helped obscure some key weaknesses in its plan and also its destructive potential. It is shocking to me that a bunch of well intentioned, well-educated, extremely rich, and intelligent folk can, in this most crucial matter, have made so many careless statements and put in place an effort with an unnecessary minefield of expectations. The potential of a Google renewable energy initiative WAS huge but unfortunately this one may be hamstrung by good intentions and a dose of techno-fantasy.

First, let’s take the attitude betrayed by Larry Page in his somewhat dismissive remark about start-ups selling 10 US cents a kilowatt-hour green power. Apparently his goals are still loftier: 3-cents or less. But we will circle back to what you are getting right now for 10 cents a kilowatt-hour in the area of carbon-free energy. We are talking about in the arena of solar thermal electric, power that is available while the sun is shining and pretty much at the lowest end of the current price spectrum; some of the very newest generation of thin film photovoltaics like Nanosolar and First Solar under good light conditions will be close to this number when the sun is shining. For less than 10 cents in high wind areas you can have clean wind power when the wind is blowing. If you are lucky to live near a strong river or conventional geothermal resource, you can have clean power round the clock for most of the year for ten cents or less per kWh. These are in their current configurations not scalable coal-replacements either because of the limited availability or inconsistent energy flow. To scale to the needs of the grid in industrial societies you are still going to need a lot of new additional energy storage or coal or another polluting form of energy, which either means carbon pollution or substantial additional costs per kWh. So we have no 10 cent per kilowatt-hour renewable coal alternative now.

The technology that currently has the greatest chance for scaling rapidly to be a coal replacement is solar thermal electric a.k.a. Concentrating Solar Power/CSP with enough thermal storage and solar collectors to bridge day and night. In the 1980’s one CSP plant was built with the capability to generate power around the clock, but informal estimates put costs for a commercial version of these plants somewhere in the area of 25 cents/ kWh in their first generation in the sunniest areas of the world. By contrast a plant with no storage, i.e. clean solar power only during the daytime, is now somewhere in the area of 10-12 cents/kWh. In either configuration, these are very large power plants costing at commercial scale some fraction of a billion dollars or more.

If Google is putting itself in the business of putting coal out of business (or at least on the run) within a period of years it is saying that as a power business and manufacturing novice it will create a scalable power plant at 12% of the current estimated cost ($.03 to $.25) for the first generation of baseload solar thermal plants. Therefore, unless there is something magical about computer engineering, charitable intention, or great wealth that transfers to power plant engineering and manufacturing, Google would be very lucky and skillful to create a coal-replacement solar (or wind) plant at 10-cents per kilowatt-hour within a period of years.

Furthermore, such a scalable 10-cent per kilowatt-hour renewable energy baseload power plant would not only represent an enormous advance but also would seriously compete with natural gas generation and for the climate conscious populations of the world stimulate huge demand as a baseload coal replacement. Ways could be found through carbon-sensitive policy to bring such power plants online very quickly. As manufacturing techniques improved, those power plants would become more affordable for the developing world, especially as those governments start to assign a pricetag to local air pollution let alone GHG emissions. If this segmentation in time is the “environment vs. development” argument that the Davos organizers wanted to spur, it is a provocative conversation starter but may not be doing either issue justice.

Reality Check: Power Density, Accessibility, Storage, and Construction Costs

As I have been emphasizing in my series on the Renewable Electron Economy, fossil and fissionable fuels are notably energy dense. They represent a lot of stored energy per unit weight and volume. This energy density leads to a high power density, in the form of the radiation of heat and expansion of gases, of the reactions that convert these fuels into usable energy. The energy density of the fuels and the power density of the energy conversion process means that, while large, the fossil fuel or nuclear power plants can generate a lot of power with a relatively small footprint, meaning less (expensive) architecture and machinery per unit power. While mining the coal, uranium or natural gas, increases the footprint of the entire power system, these stamps on the landscape are holes or penetrations into the earth rather than relatively more expensive pieces of architecture and machinery.

By contrast, renewable energy has in most of its accessible forms a lower power density than a coal fire or a nuclear chain reaction: organisms would be destroyed by the high energy flux in the form of heat, so the biosphere flourishes more under moderate energy flux conditions. The highest naturally occurring power density can be found in limited or inaccessible areas of the world: high-volume rapidly flowing rivers (one of the few hospitable high energy areas for life), the hottest geothermal wells reaching deep in earth’s crust or mantle, and high in the jet streams. For the highest power density streams of renewable energy, there are then either limitations of scale or notable physical and therefore investment challenges to accessing it.

The more accessible and easily scalable renewable energy with lower power density requires larger power plants to capture the same amount of energy as is found in a coal pile, natural gas well or enriched uranium. Power plant engineers can correct me on this but back of the envelope calculations indicate that the average power density at the heat exchange surfaces of a coal fired power plant is about 3,000 times the average power density of the desert sunlight, averaged day and night. Furthermore most of this energy flux is intermittent or periodic. Therefore additional storage needs to be constructed, an additional expense.

The point I am getting at is that power plants and particularly scalable renewable power plants that can replace coal, are, for the time being, very large construction projects that require substantial initial investment and, potentially, a fairly long innovation curve to reduce costs. Unless someone shows me an argument based on physics rather than wishful thinking that this scale issue can be circumvented, I think it is prudent to continue down the path that assumes that they will start being more expensive until we get some more experience building them; it is not for a lack of “moxy” or imagination that clean power plants are currently at this juncture. Therefore the per unit energy cost will be high until there is an evolution or revolutions in manufacturing to the point where they are affordable for most of the world’s people. We have only recently decided that coal is not “cool” so it is highly unlikely that the first generation of coal replacement plants will suddenly dip below the energy costs of natural gas plants, let alone coal.

Furthermore, Google has not had as its business focus the manufacture of objects that live in the outdoors in the elements. Its main products on the market are valued for their ability to process signs and symbols in ways that are useful to people though they are based on energy efficient server architecture that needs to manage power and heat as a energy consumer. In fact, some of the superheated price expectations behind RE<C may be fueled by the way Google’s and other software/Internet businesses have been built on the platform of Moore’s Law, which has allowed computing energy to go down as computing power has gone up: few businesses in history have lived in an environment where the development and efficiency curve has been so rapid due to this happy intersection of factors. In their own “Google engineering” self-image they may be downplaying the work done by many materials scientists, physicists and chip designers at Intel, AMD, AMAT, etc. Yes, the wealth that Google and the Google founders have harvested from their business enables the purchase of or construction of large physical objects and of intellectual property but this is not the same thing as making cheaply the big and/or remotely situated things that we need to generate clean power. They might do wonders but it is not a short leap which they are proposing.

Google vs. the Clean Power Industry

In the Davos session, there was a sense that Google sees the evolution of the renewable energy industry as prologue to its own efforts, especially with its insistence on the low price point. Beyond the particulars of that session, RE<C sets it up to diminish rather than promote the existing efforts of companies in that industry as it hoping to leapfrog by a really significant margin, the price-points that seem to be fair and reasonable to that industry in at least the developed but also in the richer parts of the developing world. The implication is that

  1. Existing renewable energy companies and their engineers are not bright enough; Google engineers can step in and do a better job practically from day one.
  2. There hasn’t been the motivation in the renewable energy industry to become more efficient and cheaper until Google has come along and declared this goal
  3. Scalable coal replacement via renewable energy is a trivial technical and economic problem compared reducing the cost of renewable power
  4. Google’s investments will be qualitatively different than those of venture capitalists who have already been investing in cleantech for a number of years

But an insulting or arrogant attitude is really the least of the damage that Google’s RE<C can do to the renewable power industry that it is at the same time hoping to join

More importantly, Google is confirming the price expectations of the public that electric energy SHOULD be $.03 or less per kWh without ever itself being on the hook for producing a clean power generator that competes on the power plant market. It doesn’t yet know how to run a sausage business and it is saying that all sausages should contain truffles at the same price as the cheapest sausage. As Google has developed a reputation, to this point, of being smart and successful, and possesses a huge megaphone, it reinforces popular expectation that high prices for clean energy mean someone is making out like a bandit, is intellectually lazy, or that inefficiencies are rife within the clean power industry. In this way, Google, itself a large consumer of power, is talking as if it is a power producer even though it may more accurately be viewed as a power super-consumer. As there are often divergent interests in negotiating the final price of goods between buyer and seller, Google, which has never marketed power, appears to be functioning as a fifth column within the industry it has just dipped its toe into.

In some of its public statements, Google has expressed concern about the “Valley of Death” that faces new power generating technologies in the early commercialization stages. The “Cheap Energy Contract” and Google’s reinforcement of it only deepens this Valley of Death; in the current investment environment, most clean energy companies are selling proportionally more of their products in European countries where there are premium payments for cleanly generated electricity as well as stronger government commitment to renewable energy than in the US currently.

Power plant investors, utilities, policymakers and public utilities commissions, if they take Google’s RE<C bluff seriously, are going to be sitting on their hands when a renewable energy plant builder comes up with a perfectly good scalable renewable coal replacement plant at somewhere in the area of $0.10 to $0.25/kWh. They’ll say to themselves, “why should we commission this plant when the Google guys are going to come up with something at a fraction of the cost in a couple years time?” Thus yawns the Valley of Death even wider.

Paradoxically, in the absence of actual prototypes with transparent cost accounting or without a good physical, technological, supply-side rationale for their assertions, Google may be reinforcing the position of the coal industry. It is the coal industry that has specialized in cheap but dirty energy supply. Applying the criteria of cheap (and controllable output), utilities and public utilities commissioners are likely to build and permit more coal plants. Contrary to what Google representatives seem to feel, there is little news value in their assertions that energy should be cheap; yes linking this with the needs of the developing world puts a charitable twist to it but otherwise it is nothing that renewable energy technology companies haven’t heard before from utilities and regulators.

Making the Perfect the Enemy of the Good

I learned the phrase “making the perfect the enemy of the good” a few years ago and am glad Voltaire invented this pithy warning of the dangers of perfectionism. RE<C is clearly making the perfect the enemy of the good, as highlighted above. Google wants to enter the energy market as the perfect participant: low price, clean (and I assume capable of replacing coal). On the way, aspersions are cast upon the good (better policy, reasonably priced alternatives).

Spectatorship vs. Action

Following from the search for the perfect, taking action on climate (part of the whole point of the maneuver) is delayed as we search for the perfect. We are invited to become spectators as buyers, investors, and activists, as the wizards go to work. We don’t start where we are but wait for the much better solution, which may not ever arrive or may not arrive on time. This is a trivial matter for people waiting for the newest flat-screen TV but in the area of climate introduces delay in introducing better policy and starting with the technologies that are achievable today. These delays will affect all of us, not just Google’s reputation and bottom line.

Google: DOE substitute?

If instead of increased electric rates, Google is suggesting that massive early investments by private investors will bridge the “Valley of Death”, I believe they are overlooking the problem of scale, risk, and return on investment. To build massive prototype power plants of a new type requires tens if not hundreds of millions of dollars, at which point one is not even yet developing the manufacturing base to get to the low, low coal price for renewable energy. Furthermore, there are very large risks associated with these types of investments. As an example, think of the risks associated with floating a large mechanical object like a wind turbine in the jetstream tethered by a long electric cable; these are not simply soft weather balloons, even if Makani will use kites as part of the rotors. To absorb these risks, private capital needs very substantial returns, which in turn boosts the costs of the plants and the resulting energy.

Historically, investments of this type of scale and risk have been heavily subsidized by or fully funded by the government. With the exception of a push in the years after the 1973 oil shock, the Department of Energy has not fully funded clean energy with the goal of energy independence via using renewable energy. Google and the Google guys have grown up in an area of lesser government ability or inclination to fund clean energy, so maybe have not conceived of a DOE that funds both early research and also facilitates early commercialization efforts. In fact, they may see themselves as white knights with regard to government funding of research, as apparently they have developed a deal where NASA uses their private jets for research.

I don’t think Google with all its wealth can afford to substitute for a Department of Energy that does not have stockholders to answer to and can survive large losses on exploratory research. Furthermore, private companies cannot substitute for the rule-making and framework creating ability of governments. Maybe Larry and Sergey’s short historical timeframe and great wealth have blinded them to the potential of government to help them and the power industry get clean energy to market. Though I am open to reasonable counterarguments, energy subsidy has been a part of the energy game for a very long time and it seems to be more a question of the goals and amount of that subsidy than a complete substitution of private for public investment.

Reforming Google’s Renewable Energy Programs

As I appreciate most of what Google has done so far in the area of Energy and Climate, I am hoping that they can change the direction of their renewable energy programs to act as a facilitator of the transformation of our energy system in the direction of clean energy sources. Investing as they have in start-ups is a good idea and should be applauded. Getting involved in energy policy debates that facilitate the building of clean power plants is a step in the right direction. However, larding on top of this the demand and insistence that the products be priced extremely low with no reality-based cost-accounting and physics-based technological rationale, weakens the effect of Google’s plans and tampers with the effectiveness of renewable energy technology firms that can deliver clean power plants at prices within the price range of energy consumers in more developed societies.

To make the energy business work, as new demands are placed on it in the form of carbon-reduction and sustainability, consumers and/or tax-payers are eventually going to need to help finance the building of a massive new clean energy infrastructure, through investments in renewable home energy generators, the spending of tax dollars on clean energy and/or through electric rates. Google’s RE<C is perhaps a noble but not particularly well thought-out attempt to circumvent what is ultimately a reality constraint on our wishes for a better world.

I am in agreement with the Google folk that this is largely about technology but the question is what is the acceptable market entry price and what is the expectable and realistic cost reduction curve that will underlie the price of achievable technologies. So I am no techno-pessimist, though perhaps I am less prey to wishful thinking about the convergence of multiple technological innovations within a short time frame. Google doesn’t let wishful thinking set the price for Adwords; why should it guide their new energy venture?

About these ads

Comments»

1. Mardell Marozzi - December 8, 2010

I tried to publish a comment before, however it has not shown up. Is there something wrong with your spam filter?


Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s

Follow

Get every new post delivered to your Inbox.

Join 172 other followers

%d bloggers like this: